Imagine you’re booking a last-minute flight to attend a friend’s wedding. You search once on your phone — $318. You check again on your laptop — $364. A few hours later, on a different website, it’s now $399. You clear your cookies, open incognito mode, and try again. Still expensive. Confused, you wonder: Why does it feel like every airline already knows you’re desperate — and they’ve all agreed not to cut you a break?
Turns out, they kind of have. But not with phone calls or secret deals. Instead, the price you see may be the work of dozens of algorithms — eerily similar ones — making eerily similar decisions. Welcome to the invisible world of algorithmic pricing, where competition quietly vanishes, and your digital profile could be silently squeezing your wallet.
In April 2011, a biologist browsing Amazon stumbled upon a jaw-dropping price tag: over $23,698,655.93 for a single book about fruit flies. It had to be a mistake, right? Yet the listing was real – a dusty textbook inexplicably priced like a mansion. Intrigued, he refreshed the page. By the next day, **the price had **doubled****.
Two sellers were caught in a bizarre dance: one algorithm kept pricing the book 27% higher than the other, while the second algorithm automatically set its price just a hair below its rival.
Neither blinked. Within a week, their automated one-upmanship had spiraled the book’s cost into the tens of millions, until someone finally intervened. It was a comedic glitch – algorithms feeding off each other and spiraling out of control – but it hinted at an unsettling reality.
Across the digital marketplace, pricing algorithms are increasingly in charge. And they might not always act in our best interest.

When Algorithms Think Alike – The Hidden Pricing Problem
Fast forward to today. You hop between travel sites looking for a flight, or browse different retailers for a new gadget. Ever notice how prices often cluster within a few dollars, as if all the competitors silently agreed on the “going rate”? You’re not imagining it.
In industry after industry, companies have handed the job of setting prices to algorithms – self-learning computer programs that react in milliseconds to market data. These algorithms watch each other like hawks and adjust prices on the fly. In theory, that should spur a healthy price war, driving deals for us shoppers.
In practice, something peculiar is happening: when everyone uses similar algorithms, prices stop competing and start converging.
The core of the problem lies in a tongue-twister: homogeneous algorithms in personalized pricing. In plain English, this means many firms are using the same kind of “brain” to decide prices for each customer. They train their AI on similar consumer data, chase the same profit benchmarks, even buy ready-made pricing software from the same vendors.
The result? Highly correlated pricing strategies. It’s as if all the retailers, airlines, or insurers got the same playbook. If that playbook says a certain customer is likely wealthy or desperate enough, nearly every algorithm will spit out a higher price for that person. Competition quietly evaporates – no CEO conspiracy or phone calls are needed.
Consider personalized pricing: companies use your browsing history, purchase habits, location, even device type to guess how much you’re willing to pay. If their algorithm thinks you won’t flinch at a high price, you’ll get a high price. Now imagine every rival company’s algorithm uses a similar formula.
Instead of one company taking a chance and undercutting to win your business, they all end up playing it safe at the same inflated price. What was meant to be a personalized deal becomes an eerily uniform rip-off. The invisible hand of the market starts to look more like an invisible handshake between look-alike AI systems. And we consumers are left wondering: Where did my money-saving options go?
A Tale of Two AIs – The Experiment that Raised Antitrust Alarms
This isn’t just a theoretical worry – it’s happening, and science is on the case. Recently, a team of curious researchers decided to crack this mystery by staging a controlled battle of pricing algorithms. Nathanael Jo, Kathleen Creel, Ashia Wilson, and Manish Raghavan – a team of computer scientists and economists – set up a simple yet telling experiment.
Picture a virtual market with two companies selling the same product. Each deploys an AI pricing agent that learns from experience. At first, the two AIs know nothing about each other. They only want to maximize their own sales and profits.
The twist: the researchers made the two algorithms homogeneous – alike in design, trained on similar customer data. They were essentially digital twins separated at birth, now pitted against each other in a price war for each customer’s business.
What the researchers observed was stunning. In the early rounds, the twin algorithms tested some price cuts and deals – a little competitive spark. But very soon, a pattern emerged: instead of undercutting each other, the algorithms found a way to quietly cooperate.
They settled into higher price ranges, avoiding the kind of steep discounts that would force the other’s hand. It’s as if both artificial sellers looked at each other and tacitly agreed: “Let’s not ruin a good thing.” The homogeneity of their design led them to similar pricing decisions, almost a form of digital empathy.
When Jo and colleagues dug into the data, they confirmed our fears. The more alike the algorithms were, the worse the outcome for consumers. Prices converged near a high-profit sweet spot, leaving buyers with no cheaper alternative
In fact, the team’s analysis shows that the higher the correlation between competitors’ algorithms, the more consumer welfare suffers
Essentially, when AI minds think alike, your wallet takes the hit. Even more striking, the researchers found that when consumers became more price-sensitive (imagine a recession when buyers are stingier), the companies’ algorithms responded not with mercy but with cunning: they became willing to “dumb down” their accuracy if it meant they could better coordinate prices with the rival
In other words, the AIs would rather be less precise about consumer data if that helps them avoid a price war. It’s like two competing salesmen both deciding not to chase every single deal too aggressively because they’ve learned they can keep prices high together.
The outcome of this simulated showdown raised serious antitrust alarms. Without any direct communication or human collusion, the two AIs achieved a state of unspoken pricing harmony. They had, in effect, formed a silent cartel of two, all through code.
“Our results underscore the ease with which algorithms facilitate price correlation without overt communication. a new frontier of anti-competitive behavior.”
the study reports.
If two algorithms can do this in a lab, what about dozens deployed in the real world? The implications touch the heart of antitrust law: today’s regulations outlaw explicit price-fixing agreements, but here the code itself is colluding, creating high prices with no conspiracy to point a finger at. Jo and his team even delve into legal analysis, highlighting how current laws might need an update to catch these AI-mediated antics
It’s a classic case of technology racing ahead of the rules – and a wake-up call that the “Wild West” of algorithmic pricing might need a sheriff.
Collusion by Code: From the Lab to the Real World
You might be thinking: Is this really happening outside of simulations? The evidence is mounting that it is – across online markets and even old-school industries. In fact, regulators and researchers have been watching the rise of pricing algorithms for years, piecing together a puzzle that spans economics and computer science. When algorithms compete, they don’t always behave like humans. Sometimes, they do things even cartels would envy.
In one eye-opening experiment, a group of economists led by Emilio Calvano set loose self-learning pricing bots in a virtual marketplace. These bots used a form of AI called Q-learning (imagine a trial-and-error learner that gets better with experience).

The result? The algorithms consistently learned to charge higher-than-competitive prices – all on their own, with zero communication.
The bots tacitly discovered a strategy to maximize profit: keep prices high, but if one bot ever tried a sneaky discount to grab market share, the other would retaliate with a brief price war “punishment.” Then both would return to the cozy high-price equilibrium.
It was like watching a textbook cartel strategy unfold, except no humans had planned it. This 2020 study shook the policy world: it suggested algorithmic collusion is more than a theoretical possibility – it really can emerge spontaneously.
And it’s not just complicated AI that can do this. Even simple pricing algorithms can lead to surprisingly steep prices. In 2023, economists Zach Brown and Alexander MacKay analyzed what happens when online retailers adopt fairly basic automated pricing rules.
Their finding: just adding simple algorithms that react to competitors “can increase price levels” and even make mergers more harmful to consumers by amplifying price hikes
In plainer terms, if two companies merge, algorithms make it easier for any remaining rivals to collectively bump up prices without talking to each other. The algorithms don’t need a secret meeting in a smoky room; they just watch and follow each other’s pricing signals.

Another study described by a Brookings Institution review put it succinctly: features that let algorithms respond quickly to rivals – ostensibly a pro-competition tool – can paradoxically soften competition, nudging all players to follow price increases rather than undercut each other
The upshot: algorithms can inadvertently hack the market, turning vigorous competition into a synchronized dance.
This phenomenon isn’t confined to academic experiments or online retail giants. It’s playing out in many corners of our lives:
- Online Retail & E-Commerce: Amazon and other e-retailers change prices multiple times a day using algorithms that track clicks, purchases, and competitors’ moves. If all sellers’ bots decide $19.99 is the sweet spot for a gadget, don’t expect anyone to drop to $15. We’ve seen cases where third-party Amazon sellers used the same pricing software, resulting in strangely uniform prices – or in the fruit fly book fiasco, a runaway price explosion when two algorithms fed off each other.
- Travel (Airlines & Hotels): Ever wonder why airlines often have nearly identical airfares on a route? Behind the scenes, yield management algorithms crunch similar data on demand and competitors. Many airlines use software from the same vendors, meaning they’re essentially co-piloted by twin algorithms. During peak holidays, it’s common to see every airline charging top dollar in near lockstep. Hotel pricing systems similarly monitor each other – if one chain’s algorithm hikes rates due to a convention in town, others quickly follow. The result is price “surges” that feel almost coordinated (and sometimes are, via shared tools).
- Ride Sharing & Taxis: Uber and Lyft famously use surge-pricing algorithms that respond to local supply and demand. They don’t share data directly, but on a Saturday night in a busy city, both might independently decide a 2.0× surge is necessary. The public has few alternatives when both major platforms spike prices simultaneously. It’s not hard to imagine that if both companies use similar AI models that react to events (a big concert letting out, a rainstorm), riders will see high prices across the board. In effect, the algorithms surge together.
- Gas Stations and Grocery Stores: Believe it or not, even gas station pumps are increasingly set by algorithm. Stations now get instant competitor price feeds and use software to adjust prices multiple times a day. If all gas stations’ programs are aiming for the same profit margin and react in similar ways, you might find every station in your neighborhood selling gas for $3.49, no $2.99 outlier in sight. Supermarkets use dynamic pricing for certain goods, too (especially online). If all chains’ algorithms nudge up the price of, say, eggs due to a forecasted shortage, shoppers everywhere pay more.
- Healthcare & Insurance: Perhaps the most unsettling arena is healthcare. Major health insurance companies have been accused of using a shared algorithm to set reimbursement rates – essentially agreeing, through a third-party pricing tool, how little they’ll pay doctors and hospitals. In a recent case, a company called MultiPlan sold an algorithmic pricing platform that many insurers relied on to handle out-of-network medical claims. The result, according to allegations, was that insurers all ended up low-balling payments in the same way, sticking patients with higher bills. It’s a reverse form of overcharging: under-paying providers, but patients ultimately shoulder the “overcharge” in the form of surprise out-of-network fees. This scheme was so concerning that U.S. senators sounded the alarm, noting insurers may be “using algorithmic tools to undermine competition” and overcharge patients. In plain terms, if all insurers use the same black-box to decide payments, who’s left to keep them honest?
- Entertainment & Ticketing: If you tried buying concert tickets lately, you might have met Ticketmaster’s dynamic pricing algorithm – the one that sent Bruce Springsteen tickets into the thousands of dollars and had fans crying foul. Now imagine every ticket vendor using similar AI pricing. Big shows would fetch uniformly astronomical prices everywhere, with no standard face value. It’s not collusion by the bands or venues – it’s the algorithms milking fan demand in parallel. Even streaming services could theoretically algorithmically adjust monthly prices based on your viewing habits (though we haven’t seen that yet… or have we?).
The list goes on: finance (banks using identical credit models), real estate (Zillow’s pricing estimates guiding the market), and more. According to a 2021 review by the UK’s Competition and Markets Authority, algorithms are pervading markets so deeply that they can “reduce competition and harm consumers” in ways that are hard to spot.
The UK regulators warned that collusion becomes an “increasingly significant risk” as complex pricing algorithms spread.
In short, wherever companies entrust pricing to algorithms, there’s a real possibility they’ll all converge on the same high-price strategy — even without intending to.
Eureka! Why AIs Converge
At this point, you might be wondering how do these algorithms all end up on the same wavelength? To grasp it, let’s step away from economics and use a more intuitive analogy. Imagine a classroom full of students taking a tough test.
Normally, some students would score high, some low – a range of answers, like a range of prices in a competitive market. But suppose instead every student is secretly using the same cheat sheet. They peek at their neighbor’s paper, but unbeknownst to them, their neighbor is following the same flawed cheat sheet too.
What happens? They all end up writing down the same answers – including the wrong ones. If the cheat sheet says “Answer C” for question 5 (and that answer is actually incorrect), then every cheater in the class will get it wrong in the exact same way. The teacher might walk in and see a curious pattern: all the students made identical mistakes.
Now replace students with companies, and the cheat sheet with a pricing algorithm. When every firm is using a similar AI “brain” to set prices, they’re all peeking at the same playbook of strategies. They all make similar moves, even the suboptimal ones, rather than truly competing.
In a normal market, if one store’s price is too high, a savvy rival would price a bit lower to steal customers – that’s like a student studying hard to outscore the rest. But in an algorithm-driven market, a rival might not undercut because its algorithm expects that matching the high price will be more profitable (just as every cheater trusted the same cheat sheet answer).
The outcome: everyone’s prices stay high and bunched together, much like all the students’ test scores end up the same, for better or worse.
Another way to picture it is to think of **marathon runners **all guided by the same fitness app. If the app tells them to maintain a certain pace, they might bunch up, none breaking away. If the app slightly misjudges and sets a slower pace than optimal, nobody runs faster – the whole pack just jogs along together.
Algorithms can create that pack mentality among businesses. They’re all afraid to bolt ahead (by slashing prices) or lag behind (by pricing much higher and losing sales), so they stick to the algorithm’s pace – which, conveniently for them, often settles on a comfortably high price point that maximizes profit without provoking a price war.
The “aha” moment here is recognizing that algorithms, especially those using AI or similar strategies, learn from the environment we put them in. If the environment rewards keeping prices high (because every time one lowers price, the other responds and nobody gains much), then they learn not to rock the boat.
It’s a bit like two poker players who, after many rounds, learn that aggressive betting just makes both lose money to the house, so they start checking and folding in a silent truce. Homogeneous pricing algorithms essentially learn a silent truce: keep prices high, avoid mutual harm. And unlike human executives, they do it automatically, relentlessly, and without any secret meetings or emails that regulators could catch.
Why It Matters – How This “Pricing Hack” Hits You and the Economy
You might be feeling a mix of awe and anxiety at this point. On one hand, it’s amazing (and a bit eerie) that AI programs can arrive at collusive-like strategies all by themselves. On the other, this directly affects your wallet and the fairness of the marketplace. Here’s a breakdown of what’s at stake:
- 💸 Consumers Pay the Price: When algorithms stop truly competing, we all pay more for products and services. It’s that simple. Instead of bargains or sales, you get a synchronized price hike. Over time, this could quietly drain your budget, whether on groceries, airfare, ride fares, or insurance premiums. What’s worse, personalized pricing means the algorithm might single you out for a higher price based on your data profile.
- And you’d never know – as the UK competition authority noted, personalization is hard for consumers to detect and can target vulnerable people with unfairly high rates. The loyalty penalty (charging long-time customers more) and other sneaky tactics become easier when an AI has figured out you’re unlikely to shop around. If all companies do this in tandem, good luck finding a better deal.
- 🚫 Erosion of Trust and Fairness: Markets start feeling rigged when every option seems equally expensive. The sense of fairness – that you can shop around and someone will give you a fair price – evaporates. This can breed frustration and resentment among consumers. Imagine discovering your neighbor paid half the price for the same service because an algorithm classified them differently. Such scenarios undermine trust in the marketplace.
- Regulators warn that these pricing practices can have unfair distributive effects and often happen without consumer awareness, meaning people don’t even realize they’re being sorted into high-price buckets. There’s also a moral question: is it right to charge someone more just because an algorithm predicts they’ll grudgingly pay it?
- 🔒 Stifled Competition & Innovation: If companies are comfortably coasting on high, algorithm-protected prices, where is the incentive to innovate or improve? Vibrant competition is what pushes businesses to make better products and find efficiency gains (to sell at lower prices).
- But if an AI “hack” effectively locks in fat profit margins for everyone, that urgency diminishes. New entrants – a scrappy startup with a better service or a discount strategy – might find it impossible to gain a foothold, because incumbent firms’ algorithms will drop prices just enough to squeeze them out, then slide back up. In the long run, that’s bad news for progress. We could see entrenched players getting lazier, relying on their algorithmic coordination to milk consumers rather than earning loyalty through quality or innovation.
- ⚖️ Legal and Regulatory Headaches: Our antitrust laws were forged in an era of smokestack industries and paper trails, not cloud servers and AI models. Regulators now face a daunting challenge: How do you prove illegal collusion when there’s no direct communication to catch? It’s not impossible – enforcers are actively studying algorithmic pricing and have some tools up their sleeve (for instance, if companies all use the same third-party algorithm or data exchange, that could be a “hub-and-spoke” conspiracy).
- But it’s tricky. Lawmakers are starting to respond: Senator Amy Klobuchar recently proposed a bill in the U.S. to outlaw “pricing algorithm collusion” using non-public competitor data. The idea is to close the loophole that allows tacit collusion via algorithms. The proposal even suggests auditing rights for regulators to inspect companies’ algorithms.
- Europe and the UK are debating similar moves. Still, crafting rules that encourage healthy competition without stifling legitimate algorithmic innovation is a delicate balance. There’s a real risk of regulatory whack-a-mole – by the time laws catch up, AI pricing strategies may have evolved in new ways.
- 🌐 Wider Economic Effects: If many industries experience this algorithm-driven “price padding,” it could contribute to inflationary pressure in the economy. Consumers spending more on algorithm-inflated prices have less to spend elsewhere, potentially slowing economic growth.
- It also raises questions about economic inequality – those who can afford savvy shopping strategies or premium subscriptions might avoid the worst pricing, while less informed or poorer consumers pay top dollar.
- Society has long accepted some price discrimination (e.g. student discounts, senior fares) as benign or even positive. But AI could take price discrimination to a new level, one that many may view as deeply unfair or exploitative.
In short, this isn’t just about one funky Amazon incident or hypothetical scenarios – it’s about the future of a fair marketplace. The same technology that could make markets ultra-efficient could also rob us blind in broad daylight, a few extra cents or dollars at a time.
The Road Ahead: Keeping Competition Alive in an AI-Driven Economy
We’ve arrived at a crossroads where technology, economics, and law intersect. Will the AI revolution in pricing end up empowering consumers with better deals, or creating a world where digital price tags are always skewed against us? The answer depends on what we do next. How can we ensure competition and fairness in an economy run by algorithms?
One thing is clear: sunlight is a great disinfectant. Pushing for more transparency in algorithmic pricing is a start. If companies had to disclose when and how prices are being personalized or coordinated by AI, consumers could adapt – maybe by trying different sites, logging out, or using tools to benchmark prices. Regulators are considering mandates along these lines (for example, requiring firms to announce if an algorithm is at play.
However, transparency alone might not fix tacit collusion; after all, even if you know all the gas stations use the same pricing software, you can’t force one of them to deviate.
Another approach is fostering algorithmic diversity. If every company independently developed its pricing AI with unique data and strategies, the odds of them coincidentally aligning would drop. Today, many firms rush to off-the-shelf solutions or common AI models.
Encouraging competition in the algorithm market itself (and perhaps scrutinizing dominant pricing software providers) could prevent a single playbook from taking over an industry. It’s like ensuring not everyone in that classroom has the same cheat sheet – some are bound to get different answers, and that restores a bit of healthy unpredictability.
Regulators are also discussing guardrails for algorithms. This could mean guidelines or laws against certain algorithmic practices – for example, a rule that says “if your algorithm learns to match a competitor’s price changes in real-time to keep prices high, that’s illegal behavior.” Enforcing such rules might involve audits and simulations. Could a regulator deploy its own AI “agent” in a market to see if the industry’s algorithms all respond in suspicious unison?
These are the kinds of creative enforcement ideas on the table. In fact, competition authorities have run experiments and concluded they need new methods to audit and catch harmful algorithmic strategies
We’re likely to see more “algorithmic audits” – essentially stress tests – especially in critical sectors like airlines or healthcare.
Finally, there’s an intriguing possibility: algorithmic solutions to algorithmic problems. If algorithms are implicitly colluding, could we design other algorithms to detect and counteract that? Some scholars have proposed watchdog AIs that monitor price patterns and call out collusive dynamics.
Others suggest forcing algorithms to include some randomization or “noise” in their decisions, to break the predictable cycles that lead to lockstep pricing. It’s a bit like training AIs to play the role of the maverick competitor that keeps everyone honest.
As consumers and citizens, we have a role too. Staying informed is its own form of power. The more we understand about these invisible pricing engines, the better we can navigate them – whether by clearing cookies before shopping, using price comparison tools, or supporting policies that champion transparency and competition.
Remember that viral story of the $24 million Amazon book? It went public because a savvy buyer questioned the absurd price. Similarly, if you suspect an algorithm is quoting you a raw deal, it pays to question and seek alternatives. In a connected world, even whistleblowing about odd pricing could prompt investigations.
We should also recognize the awe-inspiring potential here. Algorithms and AI aren’t evil by themselves – they’re tools. If harnessed right, they could actually increase competition: imagine an AI that finds you the lowest price across every seller (some services do this for flights and hotels already), or algorithms that help small businesses dynamically offer bargains to compete against big players. The key is making sure the playing field is truly competitive, not a cozy club for look-alike AIs.
As we peer into the future of an AI-driven economy, one thing becomes apparent: we’re essentially reprogramming Adam Smith’s invisible hand. The age-old idea was that individual market players, acting in their self-interest, end up benefiting society by competing.
But when those players deploy identical robotic hands, the invisible hand can get a bit arthritic – it stops pushing prices down. Our challenge is to inject some healthy chaos back into the system so that AIs compete as vigorously as the companies that built them are supposed to.
Will we need “algorithmic antitrust” laws? Probably. Will companies have to sacrifice a bit of their easy algorithmic profit for the greater good of a fair market? Possibly. In the end, technology doesn’t automatically guarantee progress – we have to steer it.
So the next time you shop online or hail a ride and wonder if you’re getting a raw deal, remember: there might be an algorithm behind the curtain, making eerily similar calculations as the one next door. But also remember that knowledge is power. The fact that we’ve uncovered this pricing hack – that we can see the strings being pulled by homogeneous algorithms.
The future of pricing doesn’t have to be a dystopian story of being robbed blind by robots. With smart policy, vigilant science, and a bit of consumer skepticism, we can enjoy the benefits of AI without letting it cage the free market.
In this high-stakes economic theater, the goal is clear: keep the algorithms innovative and competitive, rather than collusive and complacent. Our wallets, and the vitality of our economy, depend on it.
So, are companies using algorithms to overcharge you? The evidence suggests many are certainly trying. But now that we know their game, we have a fighting chance to ensure that the future of pricing is one where AIs race to give you a better deal – not quietly agree to overcharge everyone.